Schweitzer Fachinformationen
Wenn es um professionelles Wissen geht, ist Schweitzer Fachinformationen wegweisend. Kunden aus Recht und Beratung sowie Unternehmen, öffentliche Verwaltungen und Bibliotheken erhalten komplette Lösungen zum Beschaffen, Verwalten und Nutzen von digitalen und gedruckten Medien.
Some important changes have occurred in the fixed income markets since we published the first edition of Fixed Income Relative Value Analysis in 2013, many of these due to the eventual policy response to the great financial crisis of 2008-2009: new reference rates, increasing default risk of governments, more regulation and capital constraints.
Probably the most important effect of the great financial crisis from the viewpoint of relative value analysts and hence of this book was the transition away from LIBOR to other reference rates. After central banks largely disintermediated the interbank lending markets1 that had been the lifeblood of the money markets, it was only natural that banks would prefer to borrow from and lend to a central bank rather than another commercial bank. But as a result of this change, the liquidity in the interbank market declined considerably, casting suspicion on interbank lending reference rates, such as LIBOR. The final straw for the LIBOR market was the rate rigging scandal that encompassed a number of large banks, starting in 2008. In response to these issues, central banks in a number of jurisdictions pushed market participants away from LIBOR and toward reference rates of their own design, such as SOFR in the US. In fact, the move to SOFR was the impetus for our recent book, SOFR Futures and Options (Huggins and Schaller, 2022).
Since SOFR differs from LIBOR in a number of important ways, the SOFR swaps market differs from the LIBOR swaps market in a number of important respects. For example, LIBOR references unsecured transactions, whereas SOFR references secured transactions. This change alone has a material effect on valuations, particularly on the relative valuations between swaps and bonds.
On one hand, the multitude of reference rates (Chapter 11 provides an overview) for swaps has complicated the already complex relationships between asset, basis, and credit default swaps further. On the other hand, the transition from LIBOR to SOFR has eliminated the unsecured-secured basis in the asset swap spreads of government bonds, which has had several welcome effects:
A less welcome consequence of the transition to SOFR are the structural breaks in time series, for example, for cross-currency basis swaps between EURIBOR and USD LIBOR, which switched to USD SOFR. This is a general problem for analysts requiring long-term time series as input variables for their models. For the most basic of those time series, interest rates, we propose the solution of using constant maturity par yields from a fitted curve on government bonds (Chapter 8) rather than swap rates. And it is also a specific problem for this book, written shortly after the transition and hence with too little data for swaps with new reference rates to present meaningful case studies. We have therefore decided to keep many of the case studies of the first edition, which cover the subprime and euro crises and thus remain of interest, though this means that we need to carry some "historical ballast" and speak from time to time of (basis) swaps with USD LIBOR as the reference rate. Apart from these case studies, we have aimed for a complete update to the current reference rate situation.
The implementation of zero or even negative policy rates posed a challenge to analysts - as does its unwinding, which occurs at the same time as budget deficits and bond issuance soared, in part as a consequence of the fiscal response to the COVID-19 pandemic. An immediate implication for modeling government bonds is that the formerly common simplifying assumption that certain government bonds were default-free is less justifiable these days. As a result, incorporating credit considerations into the analysis of government bonds has become increasingly important. We have responded to this development by adding a term for credit difference to the term for funding difference in our swap spread model. While the sovereign CDS was already treated extensively in the first edition, it remained an external addition to the relationship between bonds and swaps, into which it has now been integrated (Chapter 12).
On the other hand, moves in rates and volatility even to unprecedented levels are the sorts of changes for which most good relative value models are well-suited or can be adapted. We provide a study of the impact of zero-interest rate policy on PCA eigenvectors in Chapter 3 and offer some remarks about Shadow Rate Models in Chapter 6. If those were the only changes occurring in the fixed income markets, the need for a second edition of Fixed Income Relative Value Analysis would be less clear.
But the move from LIBOR to overnight reference rates, non-negligible default risk of government bonds, and tighter regulation are the sorts of changes that require us to review and partly modify our approaches. The basic economics underlying our models are the same. They are still predicated on the principles that arbitrage opportunities are unsustainable and that instruments with similar risks should be expected to generate similar returns (Chapter 1). But the application of these principles via models needs to change as the structure of the market changes. And that's the primary motivation behind this second edition of the book.
The Basel III process has culminated in quite a number of additional regulations designed to improve the safety and soundness of the world's banks, especially the largest institutions that tend to dominate the fixed income markets. One effect of these regulations is that bank balance sheets face many more constraints now than they did a decade ago. And the effect of these constraints is that the relevant cost for a bank contemplating a new position is no longer the marginal cost of funds in the market, such as interest rates paid on retail or commercial deposits. Rather, it's the shadow cost of the least onerous constraint currently binding the bank's balance sheet. For example, if a bank needs to shed an asset currently generating a return on capital of 7% in order to make room for another asset, then 7% is the relevant hurdle for the new asset, even if retail deposits cost the bank much less.
The presence of so many binding constraints on bank balance sheets has a number of important implications for the fixed income markets, two of which are discussed in Chapter 18. First, relative value analysts must incorporate these shadow costs into their analysis as and when these constraints are binding on the balance sheets of the firms for which they work. Second, analysts must incorporate the fact that traders at other firms will often face the same sorts of shadow costs and that these generally won't be observable in the market. In the old days, it wasn't difficult to produce a reasonable estimate of the marginal costs that other market participants faced when analyzing certain trades. These days, we typically have very little understanding of the shadow costs faced by traders at the largest banks.
As a result, it has become more difficult for relative value analysts to produce useful forecasts about the eventual richening or cheapening of various instruments. Given that the problem of unobservable input variables exists independently of the sophistication of the model, the analytic ideal to explain and predict all pricing relationships via no-arbitrage models needs to be reviewed. While these relationships continue to provide important insights, their influence on market prices on a given day depends on the unobservable shadow cost of arbitrage capital of the marginal market participant.
Chapter 18 highlights one of the more notable instances of this phenomenon: the repo spike of September 2019. As Jamie Dimon later stated publicly, JP Morgan wasn't in a position to satisfy the demand for cash against collateral that day, due to binding regulatory constraints on its balance sheet. He also noted that this was a change for the bank and that the bank had provided additional funds in similar situations prior to these additional regulations. We presume other banks faced similar constraints on their balance sheets at the same time. Repo rates are fundamental to a large number of relative value trades, and all of these are affected in some way when repo rates spike as high as they did that day. Relative value analysts have no choice but to grapple with these shadow costs and their effects on pricing in the fixed income markets, despite the fact that it can be a difficult task.
Beside these policy-related changes,...
Dateiformat: ePUBKopierschutz: Adobe-DRM (Digital Rights Management)
Systemvoraussetzungen:
Das Dateiformat ePUB ist sehr gut für Romane und Sachbücher geeignet – also für „fließenden” Text ohne komplexes Layout. Bei E-Readern oder Smartphones passt sich der Zeilen- und Seitenumbruch automatisch den kleinen Displays an. Mit Adobe-DRM wird hier ein „harter” Kopierschutz verwendet. Wenn die notwendigen Voraussetzungen nicht vorliegen, können Sie das E-Book leider nicht öffnen. Daher müssen Sie bereits vor dem Download Ihre Lese-Hardware vorbereiten.Bitte beachten Sie: Wir empfehlen Ihnen unbedingt nach Installation der Lese-Software diese mit Ihrer persönlichen Adobe-ID zu autorisieren!
Weitere Informationen finden Sie in unserer E-Book Hilfe.