Patents

Prompting or Restricting Innovation?
 
 
Wiley-ISTE (Verlag)
  • erschienen am 30. Oktober 2017
  • |
  • 274 Seiten
 
E-Book | ePUB mit Adobe DRM | Systemvoraussetzungen
978-1-119-47373-2 (ISBN)
 
The patent system is criticized today by some practitioners and economists. In fact, there is a partial disconnection between patent demographics and productivity gains, but also the development of actors who do not innovate and who develop business models that their detractors equate with a capture of annuities or a dangerous commodification of patents.
This book provides a less Manichaean view of the position of patents in the system of contemporary innovation. It first recalls that these criticisms are not new, before arguing that if these criticisms have been revived, it is because of a partial shift from an integrated innovation system to a much more fragmented and open system. This shift accompanied the promotion of a more competitive economy. The authors show that this movement is coherent with a more intensive use of patents, but also one that is more focused on their signal function than on their function of direct monetary incentive to innovation.
1. Auflage
  • Englisch
  • Newark
  • |
  • USA
John Wiley & Sons
  • 1,70 MB
978-1-119-47373-2 (9781119473732)
111947373X (111947373X)
weitere Ausgaben werden ermittelt
1. The Purpose of Patents.
2. The Imprimatur of Patent Offices in the Face of Reforms.
3. The Judiciarization of Patents.
4. A New Place under the Sun for Patents?

Introduction


It is tempting to see the debate about the relevance of patents for supporting innovation as a contemporary, updated version of the tongue anecdote from Aesop, the famous ancient Greek fabulist who was also a slave. When his master asked him to go to market to buy the choicest dainties to honor some special guests, Aesop only bought tongues, which he served with different sauces. When his master questioned his choice, Aesop responded, "There is nothing better than the tongue, the connection to civil life, the key to science, the organ of truth, reason and prayer. Through it, we build cities and govern them, we teach, we persuade, we hold assemblies, and we carry out the most important of all work, which is to praise the gods". Offended by this answer, Xanthos, Aesop's master, asked him to choose the worst meal for the same guests to try the next night. Again, Aesop bought only tongues, and served them with different sauces. To his puzzled master, he responded: "There is nothing worse than the tongue, the mother of all disputes, the source of all conflict and wars, the organ of error and slander, blasphemy and impiety. Through it, we destroy cities, we convince people of evil things, and we utter blasphemy about the power of the gods"1.

Patents are at least as ambivalent as Aesop characterizes the tongue. This ambivalence has long been recognized. When concluding his report for the U.S. Senate about patents, Machlup [MAC 58, pp. 79-80] wrote: "No economist, on the basis of present knowledge, could possible state with certainty that the patent system, as it now operates, confers a net benefit or a net loss upon society. The best he can do is state assumptions and make guesses about the extent to which reality corresponds to these assumptions. [.] If one does not know whether a system as a whole is good or bad, the safest policy conclusion is to "muddle through" either with it, if one has long lived with it or without it, if one has long lived without it. If we did not have a patent system, it would be irresponsible, on the basis of our present knowledge of its economic consequences, to recommend instituting one. But since we have had a patent system for a long time, it would be irresponsible, on the basis of our present knowledge, to recommend abolishing it". After emerging in England, as a system of exceptions in the context of laws to counter monopoly rents, patents were conversely consecrated as a natural right of all men over what they produced following the French Revolution in 1789. Over the course of the 19th Century, calls to put an end to the patent system increased. In Great Britain, the news magazine The Economist openly took a position in favor of abandoning them in an article published in 18512. In France, the Saint-Simonian economist Michel Chevalier wrote as early as 1862 that "the legislation of invention patents is harmful to industry today" (Chevalier [CHE 62]). Some countries, such as Switzerland, refused all protection by patents, a system judged in principle to be "pernicious and indefensible" in itself3. The Netherlands abandoned the legal protection of inventions between 1869 and 1912 (Schiff [SCH 71]). The movement in support of abolishing the patent system - its "reform" as it was called - nearly carried the day between 1850 and 1875, but those in favor of maintaining the system were victorious in the end owing to the "protectionist reaction" at the turn of the century (Machlup and Penrose [MAC 50]).

The inability, for more than a century and a half now, of industrialized or industrializing countries to develop a sustainable mechanism that encourages innovation that could substitute for patents and displace them may be seen as "default" proof that patents are the best system. Even though the academic literature has considered, and continues to actively consider, the question of the best support mechanism for innovation, it must be said that no alternative solution seems able to fully eclipse patents. So, we can justify maintaining the patent system in light of Oliver Williamson's criterion of "remediableness" [WIL 96], which is to say that an existing practice for which there exists no feasible better alternative, which can be described and implemented with a reduced net gain, is presumed to be efficient. This does not mean that the patent system does not have a certain number of flaws and quirks, only that the alternative solutions are not exempt from those either. Because of this, several economists defend the system as being the lesser evil, somewhat in the manner of Winston Churchill, who said that democracy was the least objectionable of the political systems. Therefore, according to a law and economics logic, strong patents are indicative of a system of intellectual property, just like property on tangible assets, that is indispensable for the good working of the economy (Kitch [KIT 77], Posner [POS 05]).

The demography of patents, however, compels us to be somewhat alarmist. In the last four decades, the increase in the number of patents requested and granted around the world seems out of control. Just as a population living in too great a concentration in a given space generates stress, illness, aggressiveness, and conflicts, the system seems to be becoming "ill." Some people see evidence of this in the overlap of rights conferred by patents, generating "patent thickets," which would lead to a prolific rise in litigation or blocking the dissemination of innovations by a stacking in license fees. Similarly, some authors indicate the weakness of empirical evidence regarding the link between the demography of patents and productivity growth, and only see an unhealthy outgrowth of the system, almost like a cancerous tumor, in the increase of this demography. The typical agent, according to this perspective, would be the "patent troll" who hides behind patents that are superficial in substance, only to capture rents at the expense of "real" innovators. For instance, Boldrin and Levine [BOL 08], who are at the forefront of the contemporary movement of patent contestation, criticize the idea that patents would lead to a higher rate of innovations. Based on the number of innovations presented at international trade fairs, they argue that in the 19th Century, countries that did not have a patent system were no less innovative than the countries that did have one. According to economists who support this slightly Manichean approach to patents (and they are no less numerous than their opponents), the staggering growth of patents is negative. For them, we must, at the very least, practice a technological "Malthusianism" by drastically narrowing the qualifying conditions for patents, or even abolish the patent system itself.

What can we contribute to such a polarized debate about the relevance of patents? First of all, we can trace the events and reasoning that led to this polarization. We can also re-situate it in a larger context. The last three decades of the 20th Century were marked by a number of economic changes. At the end of the 30 glorious years, the economic system characterized by a kind of capitalism that was tightly regulated by the State, has been replaced by a new economic system where the prevalence of markets is affirmed. It consists of goods markets based on the development of international trade and the advent of globalization. It also involves financial markets with unprecedented mobility for capital. It is not at all surprising that the model for innovation also changed in such a context. Confronted by markets for goods and services where competition is stimulated by new actors struggling to gain entry, the model of innovation necessarily led to change in the 21st Century. More actors also means that smaller actors cannot exist without specializing, including in the production of innovative solutions intended for others. However, smaller actors are also more subject to financial constraints. In order to bypass these constraints, what is more logical than to turn to the financial actors for whom obstacles were removed regarding the possibility of involvement? More actors can also mean more interactions among them. What we see emerging in this systemic logic is a shift away from a vertically integrated model of innovation "à la Schumpeter" where large firms create inventions internally, fund R&D themselves, and attempt to produce and commercialize innovations by themselves, toward a fragmented and intermediated model where a large number of actors interact with each other. These interactions require guarding against imitation as best as possible, but also sharing inventions while still being able to protect them. Patents can respond to these requirements. They ensure what economists call the appropriability of returns from inventions, and thereby encourage innovation. Aside from this traditional perspective on their role, patents also make it possible to demonstrate inventive capacities and reduce information asymmetry in transactions concerning new technologies, in partnerships forged to design these technologies, or in the access to external funding for R&D to support these technologies. This does not mean that the new system guarantees more innovations. It is only said that, while the vertically integrated system of innovation could more easily do without patents, the new fragmented system of innovation is much more constructed with, and even around, patents. That is what this book will attempt to demonstrate.

To understand this logic, it is important to start by recalling the purpose...

Dateiformat: EPUB
Kopierschutz: Adobe-DRM (Digital Rights Management)

Systemvoraussetzungen:

Computer (Windows; MacOS X; Linux): Installieren Sie bereits vor dem Download die kostenlose Software Adobe Digital Editions (siehe E-Book Hilfe).

Tablet/Smartphone (Android; iOS): Installieren Sie bereits vor dem Download die kostenlose App Adobe Digital Editions (siehe E-Book Hilfe).

E-Book-Reader: Bookeen, Kobo, Pocketbook, Sony, Tolino u.v.a.m. (nicht Kindle)

Das Dateiformat EPUB ist sehr gut für Romane und Sachbücher geeignet - also für "fließenden" Text ohne komplexes Layout. Bei E-Readern oder Smartphones passt sich der Zeilen- und Seitenumbruch automatisch den kleinen Displays an. Mit Adobe-DRM wird hier ein "harter" Kopierschutz verwendet. Wenn die notwendigen Voraussetzungen nicht vorliegen, können Sie das E-Book leider nicht öffnen. Daher müssen Sie bereits vor dem Download Ihre Lese-Hardware vorbereiten.

Weitere Informationen finden Sie in unserer E-Book Hilfe.


Download (sofort verfügbar)

92,99 €
inkl. 19% MwSt.
Download / Einzel-Lizenz
ePUB mit Adobe DRM
siehe Systemvoraussetzungen
E-Book bestellen

Unsere Web-Seiten verwenden Cookies. Mit der Nutzung dieser Web-Seiten erklären Sie sich damit einverstanden. Mehr Informationen finden Sie in unserem Datenschutzhinweis. Ok